November 5, 2014

First Reaction to the 2014 Midterms

It's been a long time since I've posted something on here, and no time like the day after the 2014 midterm election turned into a trip down Beatdown Boulevard* for the Democrats. Here's my quick take on what I'm looking at going forward, with some help from Public Enemy, Rick Pitino, SNL, and Bon Jovi.

June 5, 2014

How Brett Favre Teaches Us About Politics

I decided to go back through my social media feeds for mentions of recently released Taliban prisoner Army Sgt. Bowe Bergdahl. My N=1 findings match those of this Vox piece regarding the about-face done by many of Bergdahl’s fiercest advocates.

It may be an excellent example of cognitive dissonance and balance seeking at work. This is something we all can catch ourselves in. Or, as I call it, the Brett Favre problem.

Yes, this guy teaches us about politics.
















The “Brett Favre” problem:
  1. Packers fans love Favre.
  2. Favre joins the hated Vikings.
  3. Packers fans need balance. 

May 28, 2014

Obama's Foreign Policy: Art of the Possible or Playing out the String?

Today, President Obama chose a West Point commencement address to revisit for the public his administration's foreign policy. The address will be picked apart by many, but it is unlikely to go down in history like Bush's 2002 commencement speech in terms of importance. That doesn't mean it's not worth considering. 

February 16, 2014

Political Science Critics: Digging in the Wrong Place?

By now, most observers who care about political science have surely come across, and commented about, Nicholas Kristof’s column bemoaning the cloistered nature of political scientists. I won’t try to rehash what's already been done by Steve Saideman, MonkeyCage, and other notable scholars who are regularly engaging in public discourse. Instead, I’ll try to touch on a few things that haven’t received much attention in the debate.

In the original Indiana Jones movie, there comes a point where the heroes realize that the bad guys are “digging in the wrong place” for the Ark. They haven’t done their homework. I’m not saying Kristof is a bad guy (he’s not), but he is definitely digging in the wrong place.

February 13, 2014

Picturing Income Inequality, Part 1

With the increased emphasis on income inequality in both Washington and the media, we are certain to be bombarded with competing partisan and ideological claims about the nature and severity of that inequality. As a political scientist, I'd like to focus on what the data say and in that way hopefully contribute to the civic discourse on the issue. This installment uses data available from the Census Bureau's Current Population Survey (CPS)—one of the key sources of information on income inequality. (For the truly wonkish, I discuss these data in more detail at the end of the post.)

The Bottom Line

The evidence from the CPS data supports the following claims:
  • The richest households have a greater share of income today than they did in 1967; everyone else has seen their share go down.
  • Average household income has increased across the board, but the growth has been unequal and tilted toward the richest households.
  • The top 5% have enjoyed the greatest increase in both share of income and average household income.
  • Consequently, there is greater income inequality in the US today than there was in 1967.

The Evidence

Figure 1 graphs the share of income from 1967 to 2012 for American households grouped into five equally-sized groups (quintiles). Two things are apparent in the figure. First, there is a fair amount of income inequality across those years.* Second, the bottom 80% of American households have seen their share of income decrease, while the richest 20% have seen their share go up.



A more intuitive way to understand income shares is to imagine 100 people who together earned $100. We could divide those 100 people into five groups of 20 (income quintiles). An equal distribution of income would result in each group having $20. The data show, however, that in 2012 the top 20 people had $51 collectively, the middle 20 (middle class) had $14, and the bottom 20 had only $3.

February 8, 2014

The Russian Ruble Goes for Gold

The following is a guest post from Blake Hall, a senior majoring in Political Science-Economics at Anderson University. He is preparing to begin graduate study in business. His research interests include global finance, global political economy, investment strategy, and emerging markets. You can follow him on Twitter @SBHall765.

Lights. Camera. Action. The Sochi Winter Games began Thursday with the opening ceremony scheduled for Friday evening. What a spectacle for Russia and my key player is the Russian Ruble, will it be able to achieve gold as direct result of the games or will it be another drag/bust on the already ailing economy?

January 31, 2014

More Evidence on the Minimum Wage

In my last post, I offered a quick summary of the evidence regarding the impact raising the minimum wage would have on jobs, poverty, and economic growth. Naturally, President Obama's focus on the minimum wage this week has generated a lot of discussion in the blogosphere. Here's a quick summary of four particularly noteworthy posts.

Alan Manning at the London School of Economics has two excellent posts on the minimum wage. The first points out that the weight of current empirical research indicates that raising the minimum wage won't cost jobs. So why hasn't this conclusion sunk in? 
In spite of this accumulating weight of empirical evidence, it is still very common to find economists falling back on the argument that a minimum wage must cost jobs because demand curves for labor inevitably slope downward. Faced with a conflict between the evidence and 20th-century economic models, they reject the evidence rather than the theory – not an ideal template for scientific endeavor. But there are, in fact, uncomplicated theoretical reasons why the minimum wage set at the levels seen in the United States has little or no effect on employment. Hence the problem may be with the economics all too often taught as dogma. [emphasis added]
His second post offers a concise history of the minimum wage and points out that it is low relative to other OECD nations.

Jared Bernstein at the Center for Budget and Policy Priorities covers much of the same ground I did in my earlier post. His key point:
The question of whether raising the minimum wage reduces employment for low-wage workers is one of the most extensively studied issues in empirical economics.  The weight of the evidence is that (1) for minimum wage levels in the range now being discussed, such impacts are small, and (2) minimum-wage increases of the size enacted in the past, and under the proposals now being discussed, are a net benefit to low-wage workers as a group.  Raising the minimum wage also would modestly lower poverty and help push back against rising inequality.
Finally, John Patty has a post at the Math of Politics that clears up misconceptions about the number of workers who would be affected by a minimum wage increase. Not only would workers making $7.25 or less benefit; those making $7.26 to $10.09 would also see a wage increase. How many people is that?
The Occupational Employment Statistics Query System, provided by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, provides a different picture of how many people would be impacted by a change in the federal minimum wage to $10.10/hr.

The most recent data, from May 2012, is displayed at the end of this post.  The points I’d like to quickly point out are as follows:
  • In Food Preparation and Serving Related Occupations, 50% of 11,546,880 workers receive less than $9.10/hr, and 75% receive less than $11.11/hr.  Thus, somewhere around 62.5% of these workers, or about 5.75 million people would receive a higher wage.
  • In Sales and Related Occupations, 25% of 13,835,090 workers receive less than $9.12/hr, and 50% receive less than $12.08/hr.  So, conservatively, about 3.5 million people would receive a higher wage.
  • In Transportation and Material Moving Occupations, 25% of 8,771,690 workers receive less than $10.06/hr.  Thus, over 2.1 million people would receive a higher wage.
  • In Healthcare Support Occupations, 25% of 3,915,460 workers receive less than $10.03/hr.  That’s nearly a million people who would receive a higher wage.
  • Overall, 10% of all workers (across all industries) receive an hourly wage lower than $8.70/hr, and 25% of all workers receive an hourly wage lower than $10.81/hr.  A rough estimate, then, is that at least one out of every six workers would receive a higher hourly wage if the federal minimum wage were raised to $10.10/hr. To put that in absolute terms:
Over 21,500,000 Americans would receive a higher wage.